“The Bear Market Economics Phenomenon” is an observation of Political Economics. Wall Street Admits: ‘We Got Rich Off the Backs of Workers’ thus creating the Bear Market. The Bear Market is America's default war.
The ethic of Wall Street is the ethic of celebrity. It is fused into one bizarre, perverted belief system and it has banished the possibility of the country returning to a reality-based world or avoiding internal collapse. A society that cannot distinguish reality from illusion dies.
This site may contain copyrighted material the use of which has not always been specifically authorized by the copyright owner. We are making such material available in an effort to advance understanding of environmental, political, human rights, economic, democracy, scientific, and social justice issues, etc. we believe this constitutes a ‘fair use’ of any such copyrighted material as provided for in section 107 of the US Copyright Law.
In accordance with Title 17 U.S.C. Section 107, the material on this site is distributed without profit to those who have expressed a prior interest in receiving the included information for research and educational purposes. For more information go to: http://www.law.cornell.edu/uscode/17/107.shtml
If you wish to use copyrighted material from this site for purposes of your own that go beyond ‘fair use’, you must obtain permission from the copyright owner.
FAIR USE NOTICE FAIR USE NOTICE: This page may contain copyrighted material the use of which has not been specifically authorized by the copyright owner. This website distributes this material without profit to those who have expressed a prior interest in receiving the included information for scientific, research and educational purposes. We believe this constitutes a fair use of any such copyrighted material as provided for in 17 U.S.C § 107.
FAIR USE NOTICE FAIR USE NOTICE: This page may contain copyrighted material the use of which has not been specifically authorized by the copyright owner. This website distributes this material without profit to those who have expressed a prior interest in receiving the included information for scientific, research and educational purposes. We believe this constitutes a fair use of any such copyrighted material as provided for in 17 U.S.C § 107.
The economic crisis has supposedly started a
soul-searching process in the economics profession. Five years into the
crisis and economists still offer more of the same in response. “Create
new bubbles.” “Cut red-tape.” “Liberalize finance in the rest of the
world.” Why do economists keep getting it so wrong?
Innovation feeds on diversity, but diversity is scarce in economics.
A little-remembered episode in the history of the discipline, told by
Tiago Mata in his dissertation at LSE, reveals how diversity was killed
in economics. Back in 1968, a group of young radical economists, the
product of the campus unrest of the 60s and the anti-war movement, came
to rock the discipline. Organized by the Union for Radical Political
Economics, they called for a politicization of economics, accusing
fellow economists of ignoring the important questions and being
“instrumental to the elite’s attainment of its unjust ends.” They
rejected the “marginalist approach,” today’s mantra in economics, for
accepting the basic institutions of capitalism, and catering to improve
only its administration … marginally.
The front-guard of the group was at Harvard, where non-tenured
faculty Arthur MacEwan, Samuel Bowles, Herbert Gintis and Thomas
Weisskopf taught a course tellingly named “The capitalist system:
conflict and power.” Older Harvard faculty found the course a disgrace.
But these were still the 60s and economics was not yet economics.
Harvard-based John Kenneth Galbraith, a non-conventional political
economist, and a notable ally of the young radicals, was President of
the American Economic Association. Galbraith was wary of economics
becoming a system of belief and used his presidential address in 1972 to
support this “new and notably articulate generation of economists” that
was coming to ask politically-important questions. Not everyone agreed.
A campaign ensued the next few years to eradicate the young radicals
from top positions. Contract after contract and tenure after tenure were
denied, including to the Harvard four.
Among them, the most notable case was that of Sam Bowles, one of the
brightest economists of his generation, as confirmed by his later work.
His tenure candidacy was rejected by a nineteen to five vote in 1973. He
had received the support of the most prominent members of the
department, J.K. Galbraith, and Nobel-prize winners Wassily Leontief and
(yet to be) Kenneth Arrow. Albert Hirschman was one of the other two
who voted in his favor, as recounted by his biographer in a talk in
memoriam I recently attended in Boston and which brought the whole
Harvard affair to my attention.
Hirschman, a moderate economist, left Harvard bitter in 1974 for
Princeton and so did Leontief for NYU in 1975, after serving Harvard for
30 years, and mentoring such conservative heavyweights like Paul
Samuelson and Robert Solow. Galbraith retired in 1975 after half a
century at Harvard and Arrow departed for the West Coast. Bowles’ denial
of tenure and the departure of Leontief, Galbraith, Hirschmann and
Arrow brought an end to the notorious Harvard faculty battles between
moderates and conservatives, not only over tenures but also University
governance and student occupations, battles that had brought the
department to a stalemate in the early 70s.
The young radicals did not have the luck of their more established
elder supporters. They were relegated to universities of lesser
prestige, radical refuges such as the New School in New York and UMass
at Amherst. UMass offered Bowles the opportunity to set up an institute
and host other ousted young radicals from Harvard, Yale and beyond, such
as Marxists Stephen Resnick and Richard Wolff.
The American Economic Association judged that there was no political
motivation behind the purge of the radicals, other than in cases where
the FBI was found to be involved. The rationale, however, often used in
many faculty decisions to deny the quality of the radicals’ research was
that it was “political” and not scientific enough. Science and
objectivity in economics came to be defined through these tenure battles
not only as mathematical formalism (in this people like Bowles and
Gintis excelled), but as one of a particular kind, based on the
so-called “neo-classical” assumptions of a world consisting of selfish
individuals maximizing their personal gain. This pre-analytic vision of a
world of neo-liberal subjects was considered neutral, but deviations
from it ideologically-motivated.
Neutrality was defended by Milton Friedman’s dictum, that even if the
assumptions were wrong, what mattered was empirical verification of the
derived propositions (of course this did not apply for those who made
too radical assumptions). But as the higher echelons of the discipline
and its prestigious journals were cleansed of radicals, disturbing
questions and propositions were left untested. Few radicals were around
to verify the thousands of studies that hammered neo-liberal
propositions, dressed-up in obfuscated math, impossible to be penetrated
by the uninitiated. While economics got dominated by neo-liberal ideas
(the farthest to the left coming out in the top journals of the
discipline today is to the right of the Democratic Party) dissenters
ended up founding heterodox schools of lesser influence, or move to
other disciplines, like geography. No doubt, ex-establishment figures
like Paul Krugman or Joseph Stiglitz do speak vocally about rising
inequalities and the pitfalls of unfettered capitalism.
Yet this is too little too late. They hardly researched such stuff in
their active careers and their popular books go unnoticed by the
discipline or the teaching curricula. Younger economists are in no
position to make similar claims in their home departments … at least
not before they get a Nobel prize, too.
Next time young students of economics walk out of their classrooms,
they could remind their professors of the Harvard story: what is taught
in economics today is not the result of a noble struggle of ideas, but
of political power and force. It should be no surprise that the
discipline is so monolithic and resistant to change.
Economics has become the secular equivalent of religion.
It includes an entangled network of scriptures (textbooks), disciples
(students) and preachers (professors), trained to believe without
questioning the supremacy of the free market and devotedly working to
prove it in each and every context, defending it against non-believers.
Like the Church and the priests before them, establishment economists
will not change on their own. They can only become obsolete, relics of
the past, as the world around them changes. And fortunately this seems
to be happening sooner rather than later.
Giorgos is a professor of ecological economics in
Barcelona and coordinator of the European network for political ecology.
This article draws from Tiago Mata’s “Harvard, Radical economists and
the Committee on Political Discrimination” published in Science in Context (2009).
No comments:
Post a Comment