EPI
Employment Policies Institute
Most economists believe that an increase in the minimum wage causes
higher prices and lower employment. This belief rests partly on
empirical evidence, but also on the view that labor markets are
competitive; if markets are competitive, then increases in the minimum
wage should both raise prices and reduce employment. However, a number
of studies in the last decade have challenged these beliefs. Some of
these studies have argued that the market for low-skilled labor has
special characteristics that undermine the traditional economic
consensus. They claim that the market for low-skilled labor isn’t
competitive and employers have the power to set wages. As a result, an
increase in the minimum wage will not necessarily lead to employment
loss.
To test this claim, Daniel Aaronson and Eric French examined
government-collected price data. In a series of studies over the last
four years, Aaronson and French show that a 10 percent hike in the
minimum wage increased restaurant prices on the whole by 0.7 percent,
and prices at limited service establishments by 1.6 percent. This
result, in combination with other information about the restaurant
industry, can be used within a formal model of the labor market to infer
the impact of a minimum wage increase on employment. They find that
employment losses of 2 to 2.5 percent following a 10 percent increase in
the minimum wage would be consistent with their estimated price
responses. These findings are consistent with a competitive model but
generally not consistent with imperfect competition models where
individual restaurants have wage-setting power. This paper summarizes
Aaronson and French’s results.
Monopsony and the Low-Wage Labor Market
Beginning in the early 1990’s, research by economists David Card and
Alan Krueger sparked a debate regarding the employment effects of
minimum wage increases. In a series of papers, these authors found that
increasing the minimum wage has no—or even a small positive—effect on
employment. In explanation of these surprising findings, the authors
theorized that there were special characteristics of the low-skilled
labor market that allowed employers to obtain monopsony power—a
situation in which they would be able to set wages in the overall labor
market. Since Stigler (1946), it has been known that under monopsony
power, an increase in the minimum wage could increase employment. By
contrast, if local labor markets are competitive, it is expected under
general conditions, that an increase in the minimum wage will cause
employment to decrease and prices to rise.
Since the original Card and Krueger research, many studies have
reestimated the impact of minimum wage increases on employment, with
most finding some evidence of disemployment, although the magnitude of
these effects remains somewhat contentious.
Tracking price responses rather than employment responses offers an
alternative method of measuring the market structure of low wage labor
markets. Changes in the size of the workforce have a direct impact on
output—increases in the workforce lead to more output, while decreases
lead to less output. When output increases as a result of increased
labor, prices will fall. The reverse is also true—lower output from a
smaller workforce leads to higher prices. Thus price responses can be
used to infer the competitive nature of the labor market.
Price Responses to Minimum Wage Increases
Using a variety of government and private datasets, Aaronson and French
show that prices do in fact rise in response to a minimum wage increase.
Aaronson (2001) finds that minimum wage increases tend to raise prices.
The magnitude and timing of these price increases is striking. Within
three months of a wage hike, Aaronson finds that a 10 percent increase
in the minimum wage resulted in a 0.4–0.7 percent increase in restaurant
prices. Much of the increase occurred within the first month of the
wage hike. In the fast food sector, prices rise 1.5 percent in response
to a 10 percent increase.
Aaronson, French, and MacDonald (2004) utilize store-level Consumer
Price Index (CPI) data generated by the United States Bureau of Labor
Statistics (BLS) to separate firms by their relative use of low-skill,
entry-level employment. A wage hike will particularly affect those firms
employing a higher percentage of teenagers and other low-skilled
employees. Using this new data, the authors find further evidence that
prices rise following a wage hike. Tellingly, they also find that in
areas where a greater number of employees earned the minimum wage, the
price increases are larger than the overall results.
Employment Effects of a Minimum Wage Increase
Utilizing these price responses, along with other information about the
restaurant industry such as labor’s share of costs and the demand
elasticity for restaurant services, Aaronson and French (2003) construct
a formal model to indirectly pin down the employment response to a
minimum wage increase. In a perfectly competitive labor market, the
authors find that a 10 percent increase in the minimum wage will result
in a 2.5 to 3.5 percent decrease in employment. When the authors augment
that model to allow for the possibility that employers have monopsony
power, they find a calibrated employment response that is only slightly
smaller (2 to 2.5 percent) than the perfect competition case. These
results suggest that restaurant labor markets are generally consistent
with competitive conditions but not with the monopsony model.
Conclusion
Although recent research has sparked intense interest in the role of
imperfect competition in low-wage labor markets, Aaronson and French’s
result that higher labor costs from minimum wage increases are pushed on
to consumers in the form of higher prices is consistent with the
competitive model, but not the monopsony model. Therefore, their results
should temper interest in monopsony models as an explanation for small
disemployment effects of the minimum wage.
Download the full study in .pdf format
This comment has been removed by the author.
ReplyDeleteThis has likely been "researched" although it appears counterintuitive to established business practice where good or superior performance is rewarded with increased pay and/or bonuses. Random wage increases could have a reverse effect. Providing a million dollar contract to any player will not guarantee an increase in productivity although it might assure an increase in effort. Effort alone does not increase productivity. In some cases it decreases efficiency and output. Although an increase in minimum wage is long overdue, it might be both acceptable and desirable to stage and plan its implementation rather than just rolling it out arbitrarily.
ReplyDelete