How rational problem-solving has ceased to be "serious" among US elites.
An American flag hangs over
the New York Stock Exchange on October 11, 2012 in New York City. The
US jobs market brightened in February as the unemployment rate tumbled
and jobs growth picked up, official data released Friday showed.
March 22, 2013 |
The United States is on the verge of committing suicide.
Slow suicide, perhaps, which may take decades to fully play out, but
suicide nonetheless. The proximate event is the sequester - deep
across-the-board cuts to military and discretionary domestic spending,
originally conceived as a Sword of Damocles, but which Tea
Party-dominated Republicans now see as just the perfect budget axe. And
that's just one of several successive and mostly recurring crisis points
at which Republicans are obstinantly demanding deep budget cuts that
will inevitably slow, if not cripple the already weak economy - as well
as debilitating or destroying vital government functions in the long
run.
This comes at a time when there's actually a staggering need
to vastly expand the scope of government action to deal with multiple
looming threats of environmental catastrophe - not to mention previously
intolerable levels of unemployment, and a crumbling infrastructure.
Climate change is just the most prominent of such environmental threats -
not just to the United States, but to the continued existence of
advanced industrial civilisation as a whole - which the US can't even
begin to rationally grapple with as long as anti-government ideology
blocks even the most common sense actions on well-understood problems. A
super-power whose highways are cracking and bridges are falling down,
and which then responds by slashing spending cannot be long for this
world. If it staggers on for a few more decades, that's nothing compared
to the centuries that the Roman Empire endured, much less the millenia
of dynastic Egypt's glory.
If markets actually worked in practice
the way that they do in the simplest of textbook examples, GOP plans to
radically slash government spending might not be so problematic. But
realworld markets not only go into crippling crises, like the Great
Depression or its still-enduring younger brother, they also fail to meet
important human needs. Indeed, as conservative German economist
Adolph Wagner noted
in the late 19th century, the wealthier a nation becomes, the more it
turns to non-market governmnet spending to meet needs that markets
simply fail to meet. This observation was made well before the
widespread rise of mass democratic government in the 20th century which
underlay the rise of the modern welfare throuhgout the Western world.
Thus, the practice of state spending to enhance the general welfare has
deep historical and empirical foundations, and the sort of endless
cutting that GOP now demands is nothing short of a suicidal policy for
any would-be modern nation-state. The US already spends far less in the
way of government social spending than most other advanced industrial
nations - 16 percent of GDP compared to 20 percent for Norway, Britain
and the Netherlands, 25 percent for Germany and Finland, 26 percent for
Austria, Belgium and Denmark, 27 percent for Sweden and 28 percent for
France,
according to the OECD - and GOP plans would slash current spending significantly below where we are today.
|
'Sequestration' : A term unclear to many in US | | | |
Centrist enablers
The culprit here, however, is not just GOP extremism - which is, after all,
wildly unpopular - but
rather the morally feckless elite centrists who enable them by
obscuring what they're up to, and by painting the Democrats are equally
to blame, no matter what the Democrats do, short of capitulating
completely.
Slates's Matthew Yglesias has
recently captured the essenial cognitive trick by which centrist ideology rationalises itself by blaming the (relatively, at least) blameless:
[S]eriousness can refer both to the merits of an initiative or to its political viability. So scrapping the minimum wage in favor of a Guaranteed Basic Income isn't a serious proposal, since obviously it stands zero chance of passing Congress.
Once
you embrace the Principle of Seriousness, the way is clear for rigorous
BipartisanThink. If the parties fail to agree because one party is
being unreasonable and the other party is failing to cater to their
unreasonable demands, then the apparently reasonable party is in fact
failing to be serious. After all, a serious proposal is one that stands a
chance of passing. Reasonable proposals will not pass a Congress in
which one party is being unreasonable, so by definition the Principle of
Seriousness allocates the blame equally to both sides. Balance is
restored to the Force.
This passage captures the
essence of "seriousness" perfectly. But it says nothing about how or why
we got here, or where it will lead - all vitally important topics to
consider, but impossible to focus on accurately as long as we're
subjected to the rule of "serious" discourse. For now, we need to tease
out a few more points from Yglesias's insight.
Serious and viable
Let's begin by noting that what he's described is a form of fallacious reasoning, specifically, the
fallacy of equivocation,
in which one word is used with two different meanings. In its most
basic form, one meaning is replaced by another: "Feathers are light;
black is dark; therefore no feathers are black". Or "Nothing is better
than eternal salvation. A ham sandwich is better than nothing.
Therefore, a ham sandwich is better than eternal salvation". You don't
have to observe a dietary law against eating pork to see something fishy
about such "logic". But what Yglesias is describing is a less patently
ridiculous form, in which the two different meanings are essentially
welded together - without, of course, acknowledging what has been done.
Yet,
the fundamental fact remains: the basis of what's going on here is a
commonplace logical fallacy. That alone is reason enough to reject it
out of hand - but not to understand how and why it works. And so we
continue with three more points teased out from Yglesias's insight:
- If
unreasonable positions ensure that the other side gets equal blame in
the centrist's scorekeeping and resulting media coverage, then they are
inherently "can't lose" positions. This provides a basic floor which
biases the entire process against being reasonable.
- If some sort
of action is eventually necessary (as it is with budget issues, and
most other governmental questions as well), then the unreasonable side -
which by definition cares less (perhaps not at all) about real-world
consequences - has an increasing advantage the longer that the issue
remains unresolved, thus further motivating them to remain unreasonable.
If they start at 50 percent (equal blame), things only get better for
them over time, as the blame burdern remains constant, but the cost
pressure to do something rises much more accurately on the reasonable
side.
- The realm of conceivable alternatives is heavily skewed to
the unreasonable side, for at least two main reasons identifiable as
distinct forms of bias. First off, there's an enormous gap between what
sounds reasonable initially and what can actually work - as any
inventor, engineer, or even songsmith knows. If there's no workability
test, then the fantasy-based side can crank out alternatives far faster
and more easily than the reality-based side can ever dream of. Secondly,
because of the bias against "politically unviable" ideas, there is a
prohibitive bias against reasonable alternatives that might respond to
claims, complaints or positions of the unreasonable side, and thus exert
pressure on them to respond, change, or even yield.
A classic example of this second bias against reasonable alternatives is the Progressive Caucus's repeated offerings (
2011,
2012)
of a budget that would balance in ten years - unlike Ryan's - provide
pro-growth investments for the future, preserve popular welfare state
programmes, and include a diverse mix of tax increases that still leave
tax burderns well below historic highs. The Progressive Caucus budgets
have been routinely ignored, despite having significant support (read
about their most recent offering, an alternative to the sequester
here - when people were polled on it,
it swamped the competition,
even edging out the GOP plan among Republicans). The obvious "reason"
is that they have no chance of being passed by intransigent Republicans -
ie, "they are not serious" in the "politically viable" sense. But, of
course, they are serious in the "solves the budget deficit" sense -
which the Republican's Ryan budgets never have been before now (his 2011
version
balanced the budget in 2063 and his 2012 version
balanced it in 2040 - despite
deceptive claims to the contrary, neither accomplished any significant
deficit reduction in the first ten years). If the Beltway media had
initially decided that actually solving problems ought to be given a
high priority, then the Progressive Caucus budgets would have gotten
vastly more coverage, Ryan's would have been laughed off-stage and
- voila! - the Progressive Caucus budgets would magically become
"serious" in the "politically viable" sense as well.
Disallowing frivolity
So
why is the discussion dominated by a non-solution while a real solution
can't even be discussed? It's because the "politically viable" sense of
serious totally dominates over the "pragmatically effective" sense of
the word, and because what is politically viable is circularly defined:
extremist Republican non-solutions are politically viable because
Republicans adamantly insist that they are, no matter how laughable they
may be - and centrist bipartisan ideologues routinely and reliably
endorse their false claims as matters of fact when they do so. The fact
that they aren't even remotely serious, in the problem-solving sense,
never even enters the picture.
One further point. There is a
dynamic, deceptive cross-over effect, in which one meaning of serious -
politically viable - masquerades as the other, providing a pragmatic
real-world solution. Indeed, this is very essense of the deception
involved. After all, the game could not even get started if, from the
beginning, we disallowed ideas that don't solve the problem at hand.
Historically, the US used to do a decent job of screening out such
ideas, up until 1995, when Newt Gingrich became Speaker of the House. On
taking power, Gingrich devoted a great deal of energy and attention to
resructuring the House to disable reality checks, as independent
conservative
Bruce Bartlett has explained, including downsizing or eliminating centres of staff expertise and abolishing the
Office of Technology Assessment. That's how Gingrich helped create the world in which Paul Ryan thrives.
Code talkers
There
is another way to understand the confusion of meaning about "serious"
policy aside from seeing it as a fallacy, and that is to see it as
involving a form of "code-switching". Code-switching refers to a
linguistic practice of bilingual speakers switching from one language to
another. There are various different schools of thought about the what,
why and how of code-switching, but nobody doubts that it's a widespread
phenomenon among bilingual speakers. And linguists don't only use it to
refer to switching between different languages. Code-switching is also
used to describe how African-Americans may switch from an informal,
"down-home" to a more formal, professionalised mode of speech.
Given
this sense of code-switching, it doesn't seem to be much of stretch to
consider wonkish economic policy talk, for example, as one mode of
speech, and sports-metaphor-driven conflictual power-politics talk -
extensively critiqued in James Fallows' 1996
Breaking The News,
for example - as another. From this perspective, what I've described
above as a logical fallacy appears instead as a switching point, from
one mode to the other. But, of course, there's a sense in which both
modes are conginually operative, just as bilingual speakers are
continually able to understand one another and to respond in either
language. Because both understandings remain operative throughout - at
least potentially - one cannot pretend that the fallacy "goes away"
somehow, it merely gets submerged. This example of code-switching has an
inherently deceptive quality and purpose to it, but it can be examined
in terms that allow study and comparison with other examples, other
situations where this need not be the case.
For example, in one theory,
Wikipedia explains:
The Communication Accommodation Theory (CAT), developed by Howard Giles,
professor of communication at the University of California, Santa
Barbara, seeks to explain the cognitive reasons for code-switching, and
other changes in speech, as a person seeks either to emphasize or to
minimize the social differences between him- or herself and the other
person(s) in conversation. Prof. Giles posits that when speakers seek
approval in a social situation they are likely to converge their speech
with that of the other person speaking. This can include, but is not
limited to, the language of choice, accent, dialect, and para-linguistic
features used in the conversation. In contrast to convergence, speakers
might also engage in divergent speech, with which an individual person
emphasizes the social distance between him- or herself and other
speakers by using speech with linguistic features characteristic of his
or her own group.
This might be seen in the situation
described above like this: divergent speech that emphasises social
distance is the language of conflict - specifically, in this case, class
conflict: upper vs all the rest (but portrayed as middle vs under).
This is what's used the moment any talk of raising taxes is involved.
Convergant speech is dispassionate wonk talk, relatively drained of
emotion - as well as inconvenient facts. The perversity of the situation
is that conflictual language is used to exclude the interests and
priorities of the large majority of the American people, while the
dispassionate wonk talk is used to create a bipartisan elite concensus
that fundamentally excludes just those interests and priorities. That's
how you create an "expert" discourse of very serious people who are
utterly out of touch with the world they are guiding to catastrophe.
Which
is, of course, exactly how the financial crises was created in the
first place. Not to mention the Iraq War. This is how US elites operate
nowadays - not just in one field of politics, but all across the board.
Problem-solving and argument-winning have become two entirely
antagonistic activities, and "moderate" "centrist" "bipartisanship" has
become the creation of such profound confusion that the voting public
won't catch on until it's far, far too late.
This is how empires die. It is the exact opposite of how republics thrive.
Paul
Rosenberg is a California-based writer/activist, senior editor
for Random Lengths News, where he's worked since 2002. He's also written
for Publishers Weekly, Christian Science Monitor, LA Times, LA
Weeklyand Denver Post. In 2000/2001, he was a principal editor/writer
at Indymedia LA. He was a front-page blogger at Open Left from 2007 to
2011.
Follow him on Twitter:
@PaulHRosenberg
The views expressed in this article are the author's own and do not necessarily reflect Al Jazeera's editorial policy.
No comments:
Post a Comment